of 10
CHAPTER 17
Money, Banking, and Inflation
KEY IDEAS IN THIS CHAPTER
2. All charts and tables have been updated to reflect new data.
TEACHING GOALS
In the modern world, the use of money as a social contrivance is largely taken for
granted. Although study of the mechanisms of trading may seem rather arcane, it may
Chapter 17: Money, Banking, and Inflation
open some students’ minds to the value of adopting a uniform medium of exchange.
Students should fully understand that a world of rugged individualism in which everyone
is self-sufficient is the most likely alternative to a monetary economy.
The level of the money supply is neutral. The growth rate of the money supply has
allocative effects on the economy. Continuous growth in the money supply causes
inflation. Inflation erodes money’s usefulness as a medium of exchange. As inflation
worsens, households substitute non-market activities, which require no money, for market
activities that do require money. Therefore, as the inflation rate increases, output and
employment decrease.
Financial intermediation is an important topic for macroeconomists because of the role of
financial intermediaries in providing a medium of exchange, and because interactions
between central banks and financial intermediaries are an important component of the
money supply process. Financial intermediaries acquire illiquid assets in the form of
loans and transform these assets into more liquid assets preferred as media of exchange.
The Diamond-Dybvig model is a useful tool that demonstrates how banks might offer
insurance against an untimely need for liquidity. The Diamond-Dybvig model is also
useful in explaining bank runs and how government-provided deposit insurance may
prevent such runs.
CLASSROOM DISCUSSION TOPICS
An important tenet of monetary economics is the dominance of monetary economies over
economies without a commonly accepted medium of exchange. Yet we still find the
existence of barter clubs. These clubs sometimes arrange direct one-for-one trades
between individuals or businesses that have a double coincidence of wants. Sometimes
they arrange three-way transactions similar to those depicted in Figure 15.2 in the text.
Some of these clubs utilize credits that circulate as a private medium of exchange
between members. To find some examples, suggest a Google™ search on the term
“barter.” Ask if any student has heard of such arrangements or even participated in them.
Are the users of these services irrational? Does the existence of such organizations
suggest that monetary exchange is becoming outdated?
The widespread use of computer technology has lowered the information costs associated
with barter exchange. But such technology also reduces the cost of engaging in monetary
transactions. Marketing materials provided by these exchanges emphasize that they allow
businesses to buy necessary products and services without the need for cash. Does this
mean that barter exchange can combine credit exchanges with goods and services
exchanges? The marketing materials also promise a source of new business for members.
In a perfectly competitive world, there is no need to find more customers. Does this mean
that barter transactions are enhanced by the existence of monopolistic competition? The
clubs also suggest the importance of personal relationships between buyers and sellers. Is
this a solution to informational problems inherent in anonymous markets? In any event,
the total volume of transactions on such exchanges is a trivial percentage of all
Instructor’s Manual for Macroeconomics, Fourth Canadian Edition
transactions. It is not likely that the foundations of monetary theory will become outdated
in the near future.
Most of today’s students have not had any personal experience with significant inflation.
Ask students if they ever worry about inflation. There may be students from other
countries (Russia, Eastern Europe, the former Yugoslavia, etc.) who have experienced
high inflation. Can anyone imagine a set of circumstances that would lead to a serious
Canadian inflation problem? Would students find more inflation objectionable? Do the
problems that students ascribe to inflation conform to theory, or are they more a figment
of confusion between real and nominal variables?
1. Alternative Forms of Money
a) Commodity Money
3. A Growing Money Supply and the Effects of Long-Run Inflation
Chapter 17: Money, Banking, and Inflation
(2) Current Leisure-Consumption Choice: ,1
lC
w
MRS
R
=
+
b) A Change in the Growth Rate of the Money Supply
i) Output and Employment Effects
ii) The Friedman Rule
iii) Deflation
iv) Hyperinflation
c) Money Growth, Inflation, and Output Growth Across Countries (Macroeconomics
in Action 15.2)
5. The Diamond-Dybvig Model
Instructor’s Manual for Macroeconomics, Fourth Canadian Edition
6. Deposit Insurance
a) Bank Failures in the Great Depression
1. In this case, Type I traders would use the commodity money they produce (good 2) to
2. Consumes 1 Consumes 2 Consumes 3
Produces 3 Produces 1 Produces 2


3. Suppose that the central bank acquires K units of capital in the current period, and
issues M units of money to finance these purchases, so that
MK
=. (1)
'
'
P
= (3)
So, substituting in equation (2) using (1) and (3), and rearranging, gives
,
'
KP
rK K P
=− +
and solving, we obtain
Chapter 17: Money, Banking, and Inflation
4. The fact that inflation alters the real opportunity cost of holding money is the only
6. Asset characteristics.
i) Works of art typically have a low (financial) rate of return. The only source of a
return is appreciation in the market price. Works of art are quite risky and are
highly illiquid. The maturity of a work of art is zero because there are no future
financial payments. Works of art are stores of value, but not media of exchange or
units of account.
ii) U.S. Treasury Bills have a low rate of return in comparison to other financial
instruments. They are almost riskless due to the government’s ability to raise
taxes to pay principal and interest. They are short-maturity assets and are highly
liquid. Treasury Bills are a store of value. Technically, they are not a medium of
exchange, although their high liquidity warrants their inclusion in the L definition
of the money supply.
Instructor’s Manual for Macroeconomics, Fourth Canadian Edition
8. Production cannot be interrupted.
a) In the standard model, with no bank, the consumer has no reason not to commit
all of her resources to production. If the consumer turns out to be an early
consumer, production is interrupted and the consumer has 11c=. If the consumer
1(1 )crc=+ . Now
superimpose the indifference curves; Figure 15.1a depicts optimization for the
consumer for interruptible and non-interruptible production. The figure depicts
the case of two corner solutions at points A and B. Point B corresponds to the no
interruption case with z = 0. The indifference curves would need to be
considerably flatter for the consumer to choose an interior solution for z. Clearly,
the consumer is worse off when production cannot be interrupted.
Chapter 17: Money, Banking, and Inflation
Instructor’s Manual for Macroeconomics, Fourth Canadian Edition
9. Each consumer will invest their entire endowment of 1 unit in the production
technology in period 0. In period 1, if an early consumer must choose the fraction of
the investment, x, to sell at the price p, and will interrupt the remaining fraction 1 – x
and consume it. The early consumer then chooses x to maximize pxx +1, and the
solution is x = 0 if p < 1, x = 1 if p > 1, and the consumer is otherwise indifferent. In
Chapter 17: Money, Banking, and Inflation
10. Moral hazard problems.
a) The child is more likely to report having trouble because having trouble is
rewarded with help.